Economists Make in Favor of Free Trade Agreements (Ftas)

In the days of Smith, Ricardo and Hecksher-Ohlin, businesses were generally small and most international trade was carried out with agricultural or mineral products or produced in small batches. By 1947, however, large-scale production had evolved and much of the trade was with manufactured goods. If economists are right that the impact on the U.S. will be so limited and the benefits so small, why are so many people calling for the free trade agreement? In order to minimize the possible negative consequences of these trading blocs, Article XXIV of the GATT requires members of a customs union or free trade agreement to remove barriers to trade in “substantially all” trade between them and that all GATT members have the opportunity to review the agreement. In the event that a GATT member that is not a party to the customs union is exposed to higher tariffs on certain products as a result of the formation of a customs union, Article XXIV requires that member to be compensated for lost trade. However, as noted in Chapter 2, Article XXIV has proven to be totally ineffective in limiting the growth of trading blocs; As a result, trade flows are now heavily distorted by these preferential regimes. Economists are notorious for disagreeing, and in fact, seminars in economics departments are known for their vehement debate. But economists achieve near-unanimity on some issues, including international trade. As Japan`s economy has slowed and lost some of its appeal to foreigners, external pressure has eased.

But the same loss of momentum has created internal pressure for reform. In recent years, Japan has become a new defender of free trade. In 2013, it participated in talks on the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), a trade agreement between Pacific Rim countries, and is now one of only seven countries that are part of both the TPP (which excludes China) and the proposed Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (which excludes America). It has signed a trade agreement with the European Union. And after America withdrew from the TPP, Japan helped convince the remaining members to continue anyway, saving a deal. Gold fetishism is rare today, but a new form of mercantilism permeates the modern trade debate. Politicians and experts often avoid imports because they destroy domestic jobs, while applauding exports because they create jobs. After all, three individual events have had a major impact on the North American economy – none of which can be attributed to NAFTA. The failure of the tech bubble has affected growth. The attacks of 11 September led to a crackdown on border crossings, particularly between the United States and Mexico, but also between the United States and Canada.

In a 2013 article on foreign affairs, Michael Wilson, Canada`s Minister of International Trade from 1991 to 1993, wrote that crossings from the United States to Canada fell nearly 70% to their lowest level in four decades on the same day, from 2000 to 2012. In addition, the trade deal could reduce pressure on illegal immigration. And liberalizing trade with a poorer neighbor, they say, would be a positive example for Western Europe to open its market to its former communist neighbors. Over the last twenty-five years of the twentieth century, the global economy has varied considerably. Land and labor were still relatively fixed, although capital was again able to move more freely around the world. However, the technology was highly differentiated between countries, with the United States leading in many areas. The idea of a trade deal actually dates back to the administration of Ronald Reagan. During his tenure as president, Reagan kept an election promise to open trade in North America by signing the Trade and Tariffs Act in 1984. Four years later, Reagan and the Canadian Prime Minister signed the Canada-U.S. report.

Free trade agreements. Most economists say that`s not the case either. The letter to President Clinton cited a review of dozens of studies on the impact of the trade deal on U.S. jobs and wages. He concluded that while the signatories had minor differences, they agreed that “the impact on the U.S. economy – both good and bad – would be small for many years.” While measuring the impact of tariffs is more accurate than measuring barriers or non-tariff services, it is not as simple as it seems. For example, economists often use a weighted tariff taking into account the proportion of imports that fall under that tariff line. One of the problems with this approach is that a very high tariff completely blocks imports, leading to the erroneous conclusion that no weight is given to this tariff line. An arsenal of theories and models supports the conclusion that the trade deal would have a minor economic impact on the United States. Fundamental knowledge about international trade has not changed significantly in 250 years; Paul Samuelson, in his legendary textbook, quotes the English philosopher John Stuart Mill as saying that the benefits of international trade are “a more efficient use of the productive forces of the world.” The broader support for free trade in recent years reflects China`s success in helping those left behind, at least to some extent. The government has invested money in infrastructure and education, and has given disadvantaged areas the opportunity to join world trade. As wages have risen in coastal areas, export industries have moved inland.

A highly mobile population and a flexible labour market are also important. About 250 million people are part of China`s “floating population” and go wherever there are jobs. Many would settle permanently in wealthier cities, but the government does not allow them to do so. Smith and Ricardo saw only labor as a “factor of production.” In the early 1900s, this theory was developed by two Swedish economists, Bertil Heckscher and Eli Ohlin, who took into account several factors of production. [4] The so-called Heckscher-Ohlin theory essentially states that a country exports the goods produced by the factor it has in relative abundance, and that it will import products whose production requires factors of production where it has relatively little abundance. This situation is often presented in economics textbooks as a simplified model of two countries (England and Portugal) and two products (textiles and wine). In this simplified account, England has relatively abundant capital and Portugal has a relatively abundant workforce, and textiles are relatively capital-intensive, while wine is relatively labor-intensive. Under these conditions, both countries would do better to act freely, and in such a free trade situation, England would export textiles and import wine.

This would maximize efficiency, resulting in higher overall production of textiles and wine and lower prices for consumers than would be the case without trade. Through empirical studies and mathematical models, economists almost generally believe that this model also applies to several products and countries. Because Mexico, in a way, beats the United States at the border. Prior to NAFTA, the trade balance of goods between the two countries was modest in favour of the United States. In 2018, Mexico sold more than $72 billion more to the United States than it bought from its northern neighbor. NAFTA is a huge and extremely complicated agreement. The examination of economic growth may lead to one conclusion, while the examination of the trade balance leads to another. While the impact of NAFTA is not easy to see, some winners and losers are reasonably clear. The creation of trade benefits the exporters of the trading bloc member, which has a comparative advantage in the production of a product, and it benefits the consumers of the importing member, who can now buy the product at a lower price. Domestic manufacturers competing with cheaper imports from their partner countries lose out, but their loss is less than the profit for exporters and consumers. Business creation increases global well-being through greater efficiency.

Another important assumption of traditional economic theory is that basic factors of production such as land, labor, and capital are not exchanged across borders. Although Ohlin considered that these basic factors of production were not traded, he argued that the relative yields of factors of production between countries tend to be balanced because goods are traded between countries. Subsequently, Samuelson argued that factor prices would in fact be balanced under free trade conditions, and this is called in economics the factor price equalization theorem. [7] This could mean, for example, that international trade would lead to a fall in the wage rates of unskilled workers in the high-wage country relative to the rents available from capital and to the same level as wages in the low-wage country, and that wages relative to the rents available from capital in the low-wage country would increase and correspond to the level of the country. in which labour was less abundant. (The implications of this are important and will be explored in more detail in Chapter 8.) A second extremely important caveat is the so-called factor price equalization theorem, which states that international trade will lead to the equilibrium of the relative returns of factors of production such as unskilled labor under conditions of free trade between countries. This would mean that for a high-wage country like the United States, the wages of unskilled workers would fall, while wages would rise in countries with abundant labor. However, factor prices do not tend to be offset in industries where production costs are falling. Even if one man is better than the other in both activities, it makes sense for each to focus on what they do relatively better. .

次の記事

Employee Equipment Damage Agreement